1704602873
1704602874
8 关于廉价劳动力和机械化,参见R. Hornbeck and S. Naidu, 2014, “When the Levee Breaks: Black Migration and Economic Development in the American South,” American Economic Review 104 (3): 963-90。
1704602875
1704602876
9 R. C. Allen, 2009a, The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).
1704602877
1704602878
10 罗伯特·艾伦同意经济学家约翰·哈巴卡克爵士(John Habakkuk)的观点,即战前美国劳动力的稀缺和土地资源的丰饶带来了高工资,这种现象反过来促进了用机器取代工人的风潮。(1962, American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century)
1704602879
1704602880
11 爱德华·安东尼·里格利(Edward Anthony Wrigley)也认为,工业革命期间的生产率迅速上升是由于英国工人拥有丰富的煤炭资源。他认为从有机经济(organic economy)向高能经济(energy-rich economy)的转变是工业革命的核心。(2010, Energy and the English Industrial Revolution [Cambridge: Cambridge University Press])
1704602881
1704602882
12 纺纱工人订正后的工资,参见J. Humphries and B. Schneider, forthcoming, “Spinning the Industrial Revolution,” Economic History Review。还有一些证据表明1650—1800间英国的实际工资比此前更低,参见J. Z. Stephenson, 2018, “‘Real’ Wages? Contractors, Workers, and Pay in London Building Trades, 1650-1800,” Economic History Review 71 (1): 106-32。
1704602883
1704602884
13 Mokyr, 1992a, The Lever of Riches, 151.
1704602885
1704602886
14 J. Diamond, 1998, Guns, Germs and Steel: A Short History of Everybody for the Last 13,000 Years (New York: Random House), chapter 13.
1704602887
1704602888
15 关于阻碍供给端创新的详细总结,参见Mokyr, 1992a, The Lever of Riches, chapter 7。
1704602889
1704602890
16 J. Mokyr, 2011, The Enlightened Economy: Britain and the Industrial Revolution, 1700–1850 (London: Penguin), Kindle.
1704602891
1704602892
17 M. Weber, 1927, General Economic History (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books).
1704602893
1704602894
18 B. Russell, 1946, History of Western Philosophy and Its Connection with Political and Social Circumstances: From the Earliest Times to the Present Day (New York: Simon & Schuster), 110.
1704602895
1704602896
19 Mokyr, 1992a, The Lever of Riches, 196.
1704602897
1704602898
20 L. White, 1967, “The Historical Roots of Our Ecologic Crisis,” Science 155 (3767): 1205.
1704602899
1704602900
21 Mokyr, 1992a, The Lever of Riches, 203.
1704602901
1704602902
22 Mokyr, 2011, The Enlightened Economy, introduction.
1704602903
1704602904
23 参见D. C. North and B. R. Weingast, 1989, “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803-32;D. C. North, 1991, “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97-112。
1704602905
1704602906
24 D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, 2005, “The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth,” American Economic Review 95 (3): 546-79.
1704602907
1704602908
25 关于商业伙伴关系和防止王室垄断,参见R. Davis, 1973, English Overseas Trade 1500–1700 (London: Macmillan), 41;R. Cameron, 1993, A Concise Economic History of the World from Paleolithic Times to the Present, 2nd ed. (New York: Oxford University Press), 127;Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, 2005, “The Rise of Europe,” 568。
1704602909
1704602910
26 参见 W. C. Scoville, 1960, The Persecution of Huguenots and French Economic Development, 1680–1720 (Berkeley: University of California Press) 。
1704602911
1704602912
27 当然不止英国和荷兰共和国有议会。从12世纪的西班牙开始,议会制度逐渐扩散到西欧。中世纪的议会是代表不同社会群体的独立机构,包括三个阶层的成员(贵族、神职人员,在某些情况下还有农民),并通过征税和在立法过程中发挥积极作用来监督王室。然而在中世纪晚期,在议会刚开始兴起并获得成功之后,君主们经常拒绝召开议会,并寻找各种方法来限制议会的权力。
1704602913
1704602914
28 J. L. Van Zanden, E. Buringh, and M. Bosker, 2012, “The Rise and Decline of European Parliaments, 1188-1789,” Economic History Review 65 (3): 835-61.
1704602915
1704602916
29 Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, 2005, “The Rise of Europe,” 546-79.
1704602917
1704602918
30 关于《权利法案》,参见G. W. Cox, 2012, “Was the Glorious Revolution a Constitutional Watershed?,” Journal of Economic History 72 (3): 567-600。
1704602919
1704602920
31 关于辉格党联盟,参见D. Stasavage, 2003, Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State: France and Great Britain 1688–1789 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)。
1704602921
1704602922
32 Mokyr, 1992a, The Lever of Riches, 243.
[
上一页 ]
[ :1.704602873e+09 ]
[
下一页 ]