打字猴:1.704603432e+09
1704603432
1704603433  70  D. Acemoglu and P Restrepo, 2018a, “Artificial Intelligence, Automation and Work” (Working Paper 24196, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA).
1704603434
1704603435  71  Allen, 2009b, “Engels’ Pause.”
1704603436
1704603437  72  E. S. Phelps, 2015, Mass Flourishing: How Grassroots Innovation Created Jobs, Challenge, and Change (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press), 47.
1704603438
1704603439  73  出处同上, 46。
1704603440
1704603441  74  O. Galor, 2011, “Inequality, Human Capital Formation, and the Process of Development,” in Handbook of the Economics of Education, ed. Hanushek, E.A., Machin, S.J. and Woessmann, L. Amsterdam: Elsevier), 4:441-93.
1704603442
1704603443  75  关于人力资本的趋势的概述,参见Wallis, 2014, “Labour Markets and Training,” 203。
1704603444
1704603445  76  M. Sanderson, 1995, Education, Economic Change and Society in England 1780–1870 (Cambridge; Cambridge University Press); D. F. Mitch, 1992, The Rise of Popular Literacy in Victorian England: The Influence of Private Choice and Public Policy (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press).
1704603446
1704603447  77  N. F. Crafts, 1985, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 73.
1704603448
1704603449  78  Landes, 1969, The Unbound Prometheus, 340。戴维·米奇(David Mitch)也认为工业革命早期的工作岗位不需要工人受过很多教育,甚至不需要他们识字。(1992, The Rise of Popular Literacy in Victorian England)但19世纪晚期的工作公告表明,“识字”变得越来越必要。(D. F. Mitch, 1993, “The Role of Human Capital in the First Industrial Revolution,” in The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, ed. J. Mokyr [Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 241-80.])
1704603450
1704603451  79  Tuttle, 1999, Hard at Work in Factories and Mines, 96 and 142; Wallis, 2014, “Labour Markets and Training,” 193.
1704603452
1704603453  80  C. Goldin and K. Sokoloff, 1982, “Women, Children, and Industrialization in the Early Republic: Evidence from the Manufacturing Censuses,” Journal of Economic History 42 (4): 741-74.
1704603454
1704603455  81  L. F. Katz and R. A. Margo, 2013, “Technical Change and the Relative Demand for Skilled Labor: The United States in Historical Perspective” (Working Paper 18752, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA), 3.
1704603456
1704603457  82  P. Gaskell, 1833, The Manufacturing Population of England, 182.
1704603458
1704603459  83  参见G. Clark, 2005, “The Condition of the Working Class in England”。
1704603460
1704603461  84  但技能溢价本身并不一定意味着对技能的需求,因为它也取决于供给:只有当人力资本的需求增长速度超过供给时,技能溢价才会出现。而在整个世纪技能的供应都在增加。
1704603462
1704603463  85  G. Clark, 2005. “The Condition of the Working Class in England.”
1704603464
1704603465  86  J. Bessen, 2015, Learning by Doing: The Real Connection between Innovation, Wages, and Wealth (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press), chapter 6.
1704603466
1704603467  87  Mokyr, 2011, The Enlightened Economy, chapter 15.
1704603468
1704603469  88  参见D. H. Aldcroft and M. J. Oliver, 2000, Trade Unions and the Economy: 1870–2000, (Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Publishing) 。
1704603470
1704603471
1704603472
1704603473
1704603474 技术陷阱:从工业革命到AI时代,技术创新下的资本、劳动与权力 [:1704601979]
1704603475 技术陷阱:从工业革命到AI时代,技术创新下的资本、劳动与权力 第三部分 大平衡
1704603476
1704603477 反对技术变化的卢德运动被证明是非常错误的,只要有更高薪水的工作来替代正在消失的工作。亨利·福特在密歇根州高地公园工厂发明的汽车装配线,实际上降低了所需要的平均技能水平。他将早期汽车轿厢工业的复杂操作分解开来,改成小学五年级水平的工人即可胜任的简单重复步骤。这个经济秩序支撑了广大中产阶级的兴起和相应的民主政治。
1704603478
1704603479 ——《政治秩序与政治衰败》,弗朗西斯·福山
1704603480
1704603481 对技术进步将消灭工作机会的担忧并不新鲜。在20世纪30年代的大萧条时期,查尔斯·比尔德(Charles Beard)和其他著名的美国思想家指责工程师和科学家为大规模失业创造了条件。20世纪60年代初,随着企业首次开始严重依赖计算机,机床放缓了车间的就业增长,人们又开始害怕自动化。那时刚崭露头角的喜剧演员伍迪·艾伦在他的固定节目中提到了“自动化躁狂症”,讲述了自动电梯是如何毁掉他父亲的工作的。
[ 上一页 ]  [ :1.704603432e+09 ]  [ 下一页 ]