1704515860
1704515861
[6]Robert M. Solow,“A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics70, no. 1(1956):65 -94.
1704515862
1704515863
[7]Robert J. Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin,EconomicGrowth(New York: Mc GrawHill, 1995).
1704515864
1704515865
[8]Robert Lucas,“Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?”AmericanEconomicReview80, no. 2(1990):92 -96.
1704515866
1704515867
[9]保罗·罗默研究了1870年以来有数据可查的11个经合组织国家的情况。See Paul M. Romer,“Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy94, no. 5(1986)
:1002 -1037.
1704515868
1704515869
[10]David Coe and Elhanan Helpman,“International R&D Spillovers,”EuropeanEconomicReview39, no. 5(1995)
:859 -887.
1704515870
1704515871
[11]Philippe Aghion, Antonin Bergeaud, Timothee Gigout, Matthieu Lequien, and Marc Melitz,“Spreading Knowledge Across the World: Innovation Spillover through Trade Expansion,” unpublished manuscript, March 2019, https: //scholar. harvard. edu/ files/ aghion/ files/ spreading_knowledge_across_the_world. pdf.
1704515872
1704515873
[12]Daron Acemoglu, Philippe Aghion, and Fabrizio Zilibotti,“Distance to Frontier,Selection, and Economic Growth,”Journal of the European Economic Association4, no. 1(2006):37 -74.
1704515874
1704515875
[13]Jerome Vandenbussche, Philippe Aghion, and Costas Meghir,“Growth, Distance to Frontier and Composition of Human Capital,”JournalofEconomicGrowth11,no. 2(2006):97 -127.
1704515876
1704515877
[14]Philippe Aghion, Matthias Dewatripont, Caroline Hoxby, Andreu Mas-Colell, and André Sapir,“The Governance and Performance of Universities: Evidence from Europe and the US,”EconomicPolicy25, no. 61(2010):7 -59.
1704515878
1704515879
[15]前沿企业是靠近技术前沿的企业,其生产率接近所在产业的领先水平。
1704515880
1704515881
[16]Fabrizio Zilibotti,“Growing and Slowing Down Like China,”JournaloftheEuropean Economic Association15, no. 5(2017)
:943 -988.
1704515882
1704515883
[17]See Zilibotti,“Growing and Slowing Down Like China.”
1704515884
1704515885
[18]Boubacar Diallo and Wilfried Koch,“Bank Concentration and Schumpeterian Growth: Theory and International Evidence,”ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics100, no. 3(2018)
:489 -501.
1704515886
1704515887
[19]Verluise, Cyril and Antonin Bergeaud(2019),“The International Diffusion of Technology: a New Approach and Some Facts,” mimeo, College de France, 2019。自动专利图景方法可参阅: Abood, Aron and Dave Feltenberger(2018),“Automated patent landscaping,”ArtificialIntelligenceandLaw, 26(2), pp.103 -125。
1704515888
1704515889
[20]Chang T. Hsieh and Pete Klenow,“Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics124, no. 4(2009)
:1403 -1448.
1704515890
1704515891
[21]Chang T. Hsieh and Pete Klenow,“The Life Cycle of Plants in India and Mexico,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics129, no. 3(2014)
:1035 -1084.
1704515892
1704515893
[22]Ufuk Akcigit, Harun Alp, and Michael Peters,“Lack of Selection and Limits to Delegation: Firm Dynamics in Developing Countries” (NBER Working Paper No. 21905, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, January 2016).
1704515894
1704515895
[23]本节内容基于以下研究: Philippe Aghion, Sergei Guriev, and Kangchul Jo,“Chaebols and Firm Dynamics in Korea,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP13825, Center for Economic Policy Research, London, June 2019.
1704515896
1704515897
[24]Aghion, Guriev, and Jo,“Chaebols and Firm Dynamics in Korea”,该研究截至2003年,因为有数据可查的期间为1992—2003年。韩国的全要素生产率增速在2003年后放缓,这与其他发达国家的趋势(见第6章)基本同步。另外,或许是因为财阀企业后来重新掌握了权力。
1704515898
1704515899
1704515900
1704515901
1704515903
创造性破坏的力量 第8章 能否绕开工业化?
1704515904
1704515905
过去两个世纪中,全球的经济、领土与社会版图经历了激烈变化。如本书第2章所述,经济增长的起飞伴随着英国、法国和美国相继从农业经济体向工业经济体成功转型。但更近期以来,制造业又被服务业取代。在拿破仑统治时期,法国有2 /3的劳动力从事农业生产;到2018年,则有超过2 /3的人在服务业工作。大产业层面发生的这一创造性破坏过程被称为结构变革。经济学家西蒙·库兹涅茨在1971年的诺贝尔奖获奖演讲中对此解释说:“经济结构转型的速率很快,结构变革的主要方面包括从农业向非农业活动转移,以及近期以来从工业向服务业转移。”[1]
1704515906
1704515907
图8.1显示了美国的农业、制造业和服务业就业占比在1840—2000年的变化。我们看到,农业部门的相对规模在1840年后持续下降,制造业的份额在1950年之前上升,然后下跌,服务业的份额则持续提升,并且在1950年之后开始加速。在经济发展过程中,各产业部门出现的这种结构性变革被称为“库兹涅茨事实”(Kuznets facts)。
1704515908
1704515909
[
上一页 ]
[ :1.70451586e+09 ]
[
下一页 ]